360-361
Figure 16.2 presents this analysis graphically. Along the horizontal axis we measure the level of pollution; here we have used tons of carbon emitted. On the vertical axis we represent the marginal social cost of experiencing carbon emissions (green line) and the marginal social benefit from pollution (purple line). It is interesting to think about the slopes of these two curves. As we increase emissions levels, the MSC increases; the MSC curve slopes up. This tells us that as we increase emissions the added cost of one more unit of emissions goes up. For many pollutants the environment can absorb low levels reasonably well, so marginal costs at low levels are low. As we dump more pollutants into the environment, however, the harm to nature generally increases. [...] Figure 16.2 presents the MSC as a straight line, but that will often not be the case. For example, the slope of the MSC curve may increase quite dramatically as the environment approaches a saturation point. The marginal social benefit curve shown in the figure has, by contrast, a downward slope. At high levels of emissions (on the right in the graph), there are often cheap ways to eliminate some emissions. Cutting back a ton of carbon emissions at this level may be quite cheap. Thus, the benefits from being able to pollute are small.
[...]
We see the optimum emissions level in Figure 16.2 is Q*, found at the intersection of the MSC and MSB curves. At this point, society is using its environment most efficiently, weighing the reduction in costs from experiencing pollution against the lost benefits from changing consumption or investing resources in mitigation.
Drawing the marginal curves as we have done and identifying the optimal level of pollution is a relatively straightforward application of the principles of marginalism that we have covered often in this text. It is a more difficult challenge to empirically measure these curves. The MSC of emissions ranges from health costs, to aesthetics, to loss of species diversity, or even to increases in risks to populations from rising sea levels. Many of these risks are uncertain and some occur only in the future. Environmental economists working with natural scientists have spent considerable time trying to provide reasonable estimates of what these costs might be. It is not easy to estimate the marginal social benefit curves, which requires us to assess the costs of technological solutions to emissions problems.
366
These countries can adopt indirect policies such as imposing fuel taxes, the removal of fossil fuel subsidies, and regulations that may incorporate a “social cost of carbon.”